Seasonal Forecast Based Preharvest Hedging

Cornhusker Economics November 4, 2020
Seasonal Forecast Based Preharvest Hedging

By Eric D. Hunt, Cory Walters, Toni Klemm and
Iyore Eronmwon

Given the immense effect of weather on agriculture, skillful weather forecasts are of importance to agricultural producers for effective decision making. Weather forecasts affect operational decisions such as whether or not to irrigate (where applicable), when to apply fertilizer, when to spray herbicide and pesticide, and certainly the timing of planting and harvesting. At the seasonal time scale, say in the spring, just before planting, weather forecasts may be used for strategic decision making on outcomes, say from pre-harvest hedging (hereafter referred to hedging), that will not be realized until the fall or harvest. Historically, the lack of skill in generating seasonal forecasts has led the vast majority of agricultural producers to not have enough confidence to use weather forecasts in the hedging decision. Scientific advancements improving skill and accuracy of seasonal weather forecasts in the 21st century have occurred due to a better understanding of the interplay between atmosphere, land, and oceans, as well as faster and more detailed computer analysis of weather and climate data (Benjamin et al., 2018). Yet, the adoption of weather forecasts in decision making in the agricultural sector has remained low. According to Klemm and McPherson (2018), the lack of adoption of forecasts can be attributed due in part to a lack of stakeholder relevance of the forecast information, a lack of forecast accuracy, or simply because the forecasts are too difficult to understand. The goal of this paper is to motivate the use of a modern-day weather forecast in the hedging decision. We achieve this goal by investigating how modern-day weather forecasts are established and develop a simple hedging model based on the weather forecast.

Perhaps the primary issue with the traditional seasonal forecast is the manner in which it has typically been communicated to users. For example, seasonal outlooks issued  by  the  National  Oceanic and  Administration’s (NOAA) Climate Prediction Center (CPC) only show probabilities for above- or below-average temperatures and precipitation and where there is simply an “equal chance” for either outcome. This approach averages forecasts over one or three months, does not give insights about the expected magnitude of anomalies1, and does not provide any information about when anomalies of temperature and precipitation are most pronounced, leaving agricultural decision-makers with little actionable information.

In our approach to forecasting, we rely on analog years. Analog years are simply years in the past with weather patterns similar to what the weather models project for the summer growing months of June, July, and August. In practice, a given year generally has three to five analogs. The benefit of having multiple analog years is twofold: it can narrow the range of likely outcomes in the coming season, and it can give early warning to the possibility of a significant deviation (positive or negative) from trend in the coming season. For example, two of the three analog years from Atmospheric and Environmental Research, Inc. (AER) for 2012 had droughts over large portions of the Corn Belt. This would have provided a useful early warning to the developing flash drought in 2012 (Basara et al., 2019) for a producer engaging in hedging. A flash drought is defined as a rapid onset and intensification of drought characterized by abnormally high temperatures, increased wind speeds, greater incoming solar radiation, and rapid depletion of soil moisture that leads to a marked decline in vegetation health (Otkin et al., 2018). Relating forecast information to analog years can give agricultural producers more context of the forecast information through yields experienced in analog years.

One of the most financially important decisions producers make is when to hedge crop and how much crop to hedge. The purpose of hedging is to reduce price risk exposure. However, hedging in the pre-harvest environment becomes more complicated as the crop is yet to be produced. Reducing price risk through pre-harvest hedging must be tempered with the probability of buyback when contracted bushels exceed produced bushels and fall prices are higher than spring prices. We demonstrate how incorporating a seasonal weather forecast using analog years can lower the probability of buyback for the hedger. For the traditional nonhedger, lowering the probability of buyback helps incentivize hedging. We demonstrate our approach by presenting the results of a study in which analogs from an AER February seasonal outlook were used to forecast the deviation from the U.S. national corn yield trend for the upcoming season.

Methodology and Data Sources

To generate an expected yield, we start out by using historic United States Department of Agriculture (USDA) data of observed U.S. corn yields to calculate a 50-year trend line (1969-2018). We then calculate the deviation from the trend for each year. Yield predictions for upcoming seasons were then created based upon the outcomes in the analog years. The better the yield outcomes in the analog years, the greater the percentage (%) deviation above trend; the worse the season, the greater the % deviation below trend. Using this approach, we calculated the upcoming growing season forecast for the years 2001-2018 from past early spring analogs that were produced by AER (labeled by the blue bar called Forecast, Figure 1). Those forecasted % deviations from trend were compared to the actual % deviations from trend (labeled by the red bar called Actual, Figure 1).

The AER analog model uses comprehensive inputs to generate a forecast for the United States. Inputs include, but are not limited to, the El Niño Southern Oscillation (ENSO), surface and oceanic temperature trends, snow cover from remote parts of the world and the North Atlantic Oscillation (NAO) and Arctic Oscillation (AO) patterns. The inputs are then used for statistical pattern matching and by recent advances in machine learning to guide the selection of analog years.

A Simple Hedging Rule

We construct a simple hedging rule that relies upon the weather forecast on whether to engage in hedging or not. The hedging rule contains two important elements and can be modified by the user. First, we sell only a percent of expected production. Leaving crop to be sold at the harvest price provides protection from unforeseen events while also providing a reasonable amount of grain sold, thereby protecting farm income from price declines. Second, the hedge decision is based upon the percent change in U.S. corn yield from trend. This feature allows the user to determine when they would engage in hedging. Our simple hedging rule is designed to limit the probability of buyback at high prices, which by design provides the highest probability of selling at the higher fall prices in drought years2. An example base hedging rule: If the forecasted deviation of the U.S. corn trend was higher than 3% below trend (-3%), sell 60% of corn at the spring price (SP), otherwise sell 100% of corn at the fall price (FP ).3 We applied a $0.10 per bushel cost to hedge and an additional  $0.10 per bushel cost to buyback when in an oversold position4. We calculated per acre net revenue from hedging using the following formula in years where the hedging rule applies, that is when the U.S. corn yield was projected to be higher than 3% below trend: (Spring Price *0.6* Expected Yield) + (Fall Price *(1-.60)* (Expected Yield – Harvested Yield) – hedging cost - buyback5. The Expected Yield, in this case, is simply the corn yield at trend for a given year. Per-acre revenue with no hedging was calculated as: Fall Price * Harvested Yield. We compare outcomes from our simple hedging rule a producer selling everything at harvest and to a producer who always engages in hedging each year.6

Figure 1 Projected Percentage

Results

The median of the AER analogs produced useful yield projections, correctly projecting the direction (higher or lower from expected yield) of the final yield in 15 out of 18 years (Figure 1). Out of the 15 correct projections, the AER analog model was also able to correctly predict the major drought year of 2012. This is especially important as the drought years caused prices to rise, thereby lowering the effectiveness of hedging. For the three years during which the AER analog model did not correctly identify the direction of the corn trend, the AER estimated deviations from trend were minimal. With a small AER deviation from trend, it is not surprising that the direction of the final yield deviation was incorrect. Said another way, the AER analog model was able to correctly predict the direction of large deviations in final yields. The AER analog model appeared to be working as intended, to protect producers from hedging when droughts are forecasted and promote hedging when yields are expected to be much better than expected. Because the AER analog model correctly predicted future droughts, the probability of buyback fees appears to be limited.

For results from the simple hedging rule, we begin by discussing results when compared to someone who is a 100% harvest-time seller. We follow this discussion by comparing the results to a producer who always engages in hedging, no matter the year. Results suggest that by incorporating strategic hedging (through the inclusion of the weather analogs) into the decision framework when no hedging existed before, the producer would have gained an additional $16.28 per acre on average (Figure 2, blue bars). However, in order to achieve the average, the hedger must financially survive the yearly financial variations. Yearly financial variations in results still exist in each year as the fall price is not only influenced by supply but also demand. In the years where hedging occurred, the hedger gained in 12 out of 16 years with the highest gain being $135.72 per acre in 2013 and the largest loss being $146.70 per acre in 2010. Recall that the strategic hedging model did not expose the traditional, nonhedging producer to costs associated with hedging in the drought year of 2012.

We now turn our comparison to someone who always engages in hedging. In this case, we are interested in the value of losses avoided from not hedging when a drought occurs (Figure 2, black bars). On average, a producer who engages in strategic hedging improves revenue by $11.22 per acre over someone who always hedges. The difference comes from not engaging in hedging when a drought is forecasted. For the 2012 drought, the AER analog model suggested no hedging and, as a result, saved the producer $178.56 per acre. During a smaller drought in 2002, the AER analog model saved the producer $23.40 per acre.

These results suggest the AER analogs model, along with the hedging decision criteria, can improve the financial performance from hedging. The improvement comes in two forms. First, the hedger is less likely to be hedged during a drought year. This is an important outcome for both the traditional hedger and for producers who do not engage in hedging. Second, the hedger has price protection in years when the spring price is substantially higher than the harvest price. This is important for the nonhedger as they are passing up higher revenues due to hedging. However, it doesn’t make hedging following the AER analog model perfect, as there were years when the harvest price turned out to be higher than the spring price (2006 and 2010). The AER analog model along with the simple hedging decision criteria, on average, improves the financial outcome from strategic hedging.

Figur 2 Comparison between net revenue between hedging and no hedging

Discussion

In this article, we investigated the role of adopting the AER analog-based forecast along with a simple hedging decision rule to evaluate farm financial outcomes. Results indicate that the AER analog model and simple hedging decision rule provided financial benefits for both producers who traditionally sell everything at harvest and for producers who traditionally hedge every season. The traditional nonhedger, would have received an additional $16.28 per acre in surviving years where buyback exists. This is where the AER analog-based model performed well, as it avoided both buyback fees and hedging initiation costs as the model suggested no hedging in 2012. The traditional hedger also avoids buyback by avoiding hedging in drought years, thereby improving financial performance by $11.22 per acre. The size of the benefit of engaging in strategic hedging depends upon farm size. A farmer planting 200 acres of corn in each of the 18 years would have received an additional $58,593. A farmer planting 700 acres of corn in each of the 18 years would have received an additional $205,076.

Forecasting a drought or other regional hydrometeorological extremes several months in advance is difficult and may not be easily detectable in a summer forecast that is issued the previous late winter or early spring. However, using analog years in conjunction with a grain marketing plan appears to provide a greater likelihood of early warning of an impending drought. For example, the analogs used in this study were able to show an increased likelihood of drought in 2002 and 2012. In both years a farmer would have financially benefitted from following the AER analog forecast and simple marketing plan, which said not to hedge if the analogs suggested the corn trend would be less than 3% below trend.

This evaluation provides a framework on how to combine an analog-based forecast with a hedging model to improve farm financial performance. Our approach is straightforward and perhaps overly simple. We leave the readers to expand on our approach to best fit their operation. We do however want to note a few limitations. First, while the use of analogs was broadly successful for this study, this was only applied to corn and might not be applicable with other crops. Second, the net revenue per acre values from this study were calculated in a very simple manner and thus may likely underestimate performance from other, more sophisticated techniques. Third, this method also does not take into account related farm risk management tools, like crop insurance. Fourth, though the analogs were produced in February of every year from 2001 to 2018 at AER, the study was conducted as a hindcast, and past success is not a guarantee of future success (Milly et al., 2008). Given that AER produces monthly forecasts, the hedging decision criteria can be improved upon by evaluating the subsequent month’s forecast. If hedges were placed early due to no drought being forecasted and then a drought emerges, hedges could be removed before prices start to rise. The alternative could also happen. Developing a dynamic hedging model that adapts to new information would likely improve performance.

Overall, the results of this study demonstrate an advantage of simultaneously applying a forecasting model and grain marketing plan. We found evidence that there is an additional financial benefit in using analogs as part of a corn marketing plan, as they can help indicate whether corn farmers should hedge or not.

For additional questions, please contact Eric Hunt, ehunt@aer.com

_______________________

1 Anomalies are the deviation (positive or negative) from average.

2 Additionally, there are no hedging costs.

3 The remaining 40% of expected production when hedging is sold at harvest.

4Costs are often found in a Hedge-to-Arrive (HTA) contract. In practice, individual elevators will likely differ in costs to place an HTA and the buyback fee.

5 Yearly expected yield grew by a 2.5 bu per year trend. Harvested yield is calculated by multiplying expected yield by the realized percent change in yield. For example, in 2004 the actual yield ended up 11.8% higher than the trend and as a result, the harvested yield increased proportionally. Hedging cost is calculated as: $0.10*.60*expected yield. Buyback applies only if contracted bushels exceed harvest yield. Buyback is calculated as: (contacted bushels – harvest yield) *(spring price – fall price) + (contracted bushels-harvest yield)*0.10.

6 For the hedger who always hedges, they sell the same amount of crop as is sold in the simple hedging rule.

 

PDF

Eric D. Hunt
Staff Scientist
Atmospheric and Environmental Research, Inc.
ehunt@aer.com

Cory Walters
Associate Professor
Department of Agricultural Economics
University of Nebraska-Lincoln
cwalters2@unl.edu

Toni Klemm
Postdoctoral Research Associate
Department of Ecology and Conservation Biology
Texas AM University
toni-klemm@tamu.edu

Iyore Eronmwon
Ph.D. Student
Department of Agricultural Economics
University of Nebraska-Lincoln
iyore@huskers.unl.edu
402-472-1796

Acknowledgements: Judah Cohen, Director of Seasonal Forecasting, Atmospheric and Environmental Research, Inc.